The student movement in Bangladesh ousted Sheikh Hasina last Monday, August 5, 2024. A new interim government has been formed to restore order, end repression, and hold a fair election to facilitate a democratic transition of power. Nobel laureate Muhammad Yunus has been sworn in as the interim government’s chief adviser, and many civil society activists and student leaders who have led the rebellion are included in the advisory group. There is a widespread hope that Prof. Yunus, the so-called banker for the poor, will bring democracy back to Bangladesh after years of autocratic rule. It is therefore important to review Yunus and his Grameen model, hailed as emancipatory by the global community, including the World Bank and the UNO. We republish an article by Stéphanie Jacquemont, originally written in 2012, that dispassionately analyses and criticises the damages caused by microcredit in Bangladesh.
CC0 Domaine public - https://pxhere.com/fr/photo/957758
Muhammad Yunus, 2006 Nobel Peace Prize laureate and founder of the Grameen Bank, made the promise of a world without poverty thanks to the magic of microfinance and social business [1]. Since the main problem of poor people was, he said, that they are denied access to capital and markets, the way to release them from the grip of poverty was to lend them small amounts of money. The micro-borrowers would then become competitive micro-entrepreneurs in ultimately rewarding markets. Furthermore, the micro-loans, mostly granted to women, would serve as a springboard towards greater financial autonomy and influence in decision-making. A tailor-made programme, we could say, for the so-called “community of donors” (the UN, World Bank, development agencies in rich countries), for whom women’s empowerment and poverty reduction are officially among the top financing objectives. Microfinance on the Yunus pattern, which now embraces a wide range of activities (from other financial services, such as pension schemes and insurance, to the sale of yogurt [2] and mobile phones), is all the more attractive to official development aid players and private investors since it dismisses out of hand the option of reinforcing the social State, considered as inefficient, corrupt and keeping the poor in a state of dependency.
Money has thus flowed in for NGOs and other institutions engaged in microcredit, and many studies, often biased because funded by donors or microfinance players themselves, have praised the results of microcredit - a business considered both useful for borrowers and profitable for lenders.
Yet this glowing picture of microfinance has been seriously damaged. First there were the scandals around the Grameen: in March 2011, Muhammad Yunus was dismissed by the Bangladeshi government from the chair of this bank after a Norwegian documentary (“Caught in Micro Debt” by Tom Heinemann) [
For several years, in-depth independent studies have questioned the model of these “banks for the poor”. One such study has been made by Lamia Karim, an anthropologist, who last year published Microfinance and its Discontents: Women in Debt in Bangladesh (Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press, 2011) [
Lamia Karim has been able to bring facts into the open which are usually unknown or hushed up for various reasons. First, the fact that her study is independent allowed her to make an objective assessment of the situation; secondly, her knowledge of Bangla and of the prevailing social codes of Bangladeshi society opened doors that would have otherwise remained closed (most researchers on the subject who do not know Bangla depend on guides – hopefully honest ones - to carry out their research); finally, she chose to situate her area of research off the beaten track, far from the districts close to the capital where locals are used to the presence of foreigners and tend to sell the information they have, and where carefully selected NGO members perform “scripted shows of development” to show how successful microcredit is. [
“The economy of shame”, or how women’s weakness is instrumentalized
Lamia Karim carried out her ethnographic study in a rural area of Bangladesh where NGOs are ubiquitous and therefore should not be considered as non-State players, according to herself and other researchers who worked on the subject. The 23,000-odd registered NGOs have nearly 20 million rural women members, and in a context where there are very few State representatives, they have gained power over the population as the main providers of basic services (healthcare, education, credit, etc.) and employment. Lamia Karim refers to them as “a shadow State”.
She studied four microcredit NGOs (Grameen Bank [
The four organizations studied followed the same microcredit model, with some variations. This model is based on the creation of groups of borrowers, collectively responsible for the payment of each individual loan granted to their members, and subject to a strict repayment schedule. Repayments are collected on a weekly, fortnightly or monthly basis. The vast majority of borrowers are women, which does not mean that they are the ones who benefit from the money and have control over its use - far from it. Indeed, most of the time, the money is given to their husbands or other male family members [
Multiple lending and usury: when microcredit leads to over-indebtedness
Under pressure from their family, from other borrowers and from NGO employees, these women have to do whatever is needed to repay their debt, no matter what the cost.
One of the problems inherent to the microcredit model on the Yunus pattern is that it makes it difficult for borrowers to invest the money they receive since repayments start just after the loan is disbursed (in Yunus’s opinion, this allows NGOs to detect possible problems immediately and make the borrowers responsible) and the repayment period does not exceed one year [
Another way for these women to cope with repayments is to invest the money they get in moneylending. One of the stated goals of microfinance players is to free the poor from the moneylenders’ grip by offering them small amounts and lower interest rates (though still at about 20 % in the late 1990s) than those charged by traditional moneylenders, who usually demand a 120 % interest rate. Nevertheless, far from the fairytales depicted in the promotional campaigns of microcredit NGOs, Lamia Karim observed that women sometimes have no option but to invest in moneylending, giving loans to traders, farmers, or other NGO borrowers unable to repay their debt. Therefore, instead of reducing the power of moneylenders over rural people, “microcredit operations had effectively widened the net of moneylending” [
Twisting the principles
With their wholehearted involvement in microfinance, these NGOs have alienated themselves from the principles they once defended, and have fully embraced the neo-liberal agenda. The activities of BRAC, whose chairman, Fazel Abed, was once inspired by the work of Paulo Freire, or of Proshika, which in the 1970s organized the peasants in their struggle against the landowning elite, could hardly be called subversive as they exist today. Such organizations have gradually turned away from their awareness-raising and educational missions, and have neglected other social issues to develop their microfinance activity. Most of the working hours of managers of local branches and field-workers are devoted to the management of loans, accountancy and debt collection. A trend illustrated by the example of an NGO worker who had only talked twice in five years about education and empowerment: once during his training period and once when interviewed by a researcher. [
Another gap between words and actions is to be found in the increased targeting of the middle classes by NGOs, which are nonetheless quite ready to present themselves as allies of the very poorest. Competition and the search for profitability have led them to deal increasingly with more credit-worthy customers. A further factor, identified by Lamia Karim in her study, intensifies this trend: some middle-class women, after being refused loans due to their more comfortable financial situation, pay poor women to act as proxy members and take loans for them. Sometimes the social status and the relative power of these middle-class women in the villages are enough to force NGOs to grant them loans.
Another phenomenon was observed by Lamia Karim and other researchers before her: loans being granted for the dowries of brides. Although these NGOs claim they work for women’s empowerment, they in fact help reinforce this patriarchal practice [
Last but not least, to maintain repayment rates close to 98 %, these NGOs rival each other in creativity and immorality in the matter of debt collection. The women borrowers interviewed during the survey mentioned that NGO workers regularly resort to verbal threats, physical or psychological violence (harassment, holding, humiliations...), even to house-breaking: when a borrower is unable to repay, other members of her group or NGO workers handling her loans sometimes get repayments by wrecking her house and selling what can be sold! Moreover, during the follow-up study in 2007, Lamia Karim noted that NGOs resorted more and more frequently to the police and/or courts to settle their disputes with defaulting members.
This incredible violence exerted by the workers of microcredit organizations can be explained by the pressure put upon them by their superiors. Profitability being the key word, in case of borrower default, managers go so far as to withhold the corresponding amount from the worker’s paycheck as an incentive to be inflexible. Lamia Karim noted that the women who work for microcredit organizations are usually harsher in collecting repayments, since the risk of their being fired if the number of defaults increases is higher than for their male counterparts.
The NGOs keep up the pressure even for victims of natural disasters. For instance in 2007, the victims of the cyclone Sidr were asked to repay right after the cyclone struck! And this happened even though the caretaker government at the time called on NGOs to introduce a 6-month moratorium for cyclone victims. In this respect, Muhammad Yunus’s position is stunning. In his autobiographical (and self-indulgent) book entitled Banker to the Poor: Micro-Lending and the Battle against World Poverty, he blithely explains: “But no matter what cataclysm, weather disaster or personal tragedy befalls a borrower, our philosophy is always to get that person to pay back his or her loan, even if it is only at the rate of half a penny a week. […]. If a flood or a famine decimates a village and kills borrowers’ crops or animals, we immediately lend them new money to start up again. We never wipe out old loans, but convert them into very long term loans and try to get the borrower to pay them off […] It can happen that our borrowers are victims of disasters three or four times in one year. But no matter. The Grameen employees step in to offer them new emergency loans to allow them to start over a fifth time [
To conclude, this valuable study brings additional arguments to those who oppose the kind of microcredit practised by the large organizations internationally lauded by the donor community. By analyzing credit not as a matter of trust but merely as a debt, Lamia Karim shows how “beyond its hagiographic transcripts, microfinance is fundamentally a relationship of inequality between the creditor and the debtor” [
Stéphanie Jacquemont
Footnotes
[
http://www.cadtm.org/Muhammad-Yunus...
[
[
[
[
[
[
[
[
[
[
[
[
[
[
[
[
[