This is certainly not the outlook of most environmentalists today. They, along with the majority currents of most green parties, believe that one or other kind of green capitalism can reconcile economy and environment. As noted in the Preface, over the last decade environmentalists have expressed this viewpoint in a raft of pro-market books.
Yet embracing capitalism — no matter how green the vision put forward — saddles pro-market environmentalists with a difficult case for the defence. They have to explain exactly how a system that has consumed more resources and energy in the last 50 years than all previous human civilisation can be made to stabilise and then reduce its rate of resource depletion and pollution emission. How can this monstrously wasteful, poisonous and unequal economic system actually be made to introduce the technologies, consumption patterns and radical income redistribution without which all talk of sustainability is a sick joke?
Inevitably, one course of treatment plays a major role in all the different green capitalist cures on offer — green taxes or ecotaxation. Such taxes trace back to the work of A. C. Pigou, the father of conventional environmental economics. 172 This offshoot of orthodox economics analyses the environmental crisis as due to the “natural capital” of the environment being treated as a free or underpriced good. In this way the cost to society of an economic activity like logging (its “social marginal cost”) diverges from its cost to the logging company (its “private marginal cost”).173
The solution is to “get the price signals right”: to impose some kind of green tax174 which pushes private marginal cost up to social marginal cost. The polluter or resource depleter will now operate at a level which is acceptable to “society” and the cost of the “negative externality” in question (unsustainable logging practices) will have been “internalised” in the offending firm’s cost structure. Therefore, if governments impose high enough eco-taxes on a broad enough scale, business as a whole will convert its operations to sustainable technology and production fast enough to turn the tide of environmental decline.
It’s a measure of the intensity of the pressure for a solution that such taxes, which in the 1970s were very minor tools of environmental management, are being advanced in the 1990s as the major driving force of the “sustainability transition”. According to environmental tax expert David Malin Roodman:
Like the gradual emergence of modern taxes on income, wages, and sales about a century ago, a great wave in the history of taxation is on the horizon. If it rises to its full potential — the elimination of environmentally destructive subsidies and the imposition of taxes and permit charges that reflect full environmental costs — it will create a trillion-dollar swing in the global tax burden in favour of environmental protection.175
Lester Brown agrees:
We have a policy instrument, largely unused, for building an environmentally sustainable economy — namely tax policy. Governments now rely heavily on personal and corporate taxes for revenue, but these discourage constructive activities, such as work and savings. Meanwhile, taxes on environmentally destructive activities are typically negligible or nonexistent. The challenge is to restructure the existing tax system, decreasing the taxes on such constructive activities as work and savings and increasing the taxes on destructive activities, such as carbon emissions or the generation of toxic waste.176
This rapid move from minor sub-discipline to new orthodoxy reproduces the speedy acceptance of the work of John Maynard Keynes in the 1930s. Just as Keynes provided anxious capitalist governments under siege from socialism and communism with the justification for public sector deficit spending against unemployment, so “environmental economics” and ecotaxation equip their descendants with a rudimentary first aid kit for treating the symptoms of our epoch’s great crisis.
Ecotaxation is the centrepiece of the US President’s Council of Sustainable Development’s 1996 document Sustainable America: A New Consensus for Prosperity, Opportunity and a Healthy Environment.177 It envisages a new tax regime based on shifting the tax burden from labour to waste, and so winning a “double dividend” of reduced pollution and increased employment. Exactly the same outlook is contained in a 1993 white paper of the European Union.178 In it, European Commission ex-president Jacques Delors states that current models of development tend to “over-consume nature” and “under-consume people”. The answer is a green taxation system: one that would reverse the trend to suck resources into the economy and squeeze people out of it.
The number and range of green taxes has increased rapidly in the 1990s, to the point that Timothy O’Riordan, the editor of a recent book of essays called Ecotaxation, can remark that it they are “now irreversibly part of the modern political and economic scene”.179 Yet how much existing eco-taxes are really driven by the desire to make the “sustainability transition” is open to question. O’Riordan comments that:
… ecotaxation is a concept and a practice whose time has come. The reasons lie more with the prevailing spirit of letting markets work, no matter how imperfect, of encouraging deregulation generally, and of taxing by means other than striking at income and savings, than with a will to move towards sustainable development. The spectre of an uncontrollable welfare state and an increasingly costly ageing population adds to the drive to shift the burden of social payments on to individuals according to need and to means.180
So ecotaxation has a role to play in neo-liberal “tax reform”, but can it really push the private profit system any significant distance towards sustainability? A recent and complete expression of confidence comes in the latest report to the Club of Rome, Factor Four: Doubling Wealth, Halving Resource Use, by Ernst von Weizsäcker, Amory B. Lovins and L. Hunter Lovins. The authors argue that a reorganisation of taxes and the rules governing markets can stimulate private investment in resource-efficient, non-polluting technologies with the potential to double wealth creation at the same time as halving resource usage — a “factor four” increase in efficiency. This would not only lay to rest the spectre of resource depletion raised in Limits to Growth (the first Club of Rome report) it would also go a long way to fulfilling the main projections of Agenda 21, the program of sustainability adopted at the Rio Earth Summit.
The picture becomes all the more rosy when “leapfrogging” is taken into account: newly industrialising countries will simply jump over older generations of polluting technology presently in operation and adopt leading-edge clean and green techniques.
Embodying these technologies in the world’s capital stock will certainly require a massive reform of what are seen as “market distortions”, but this reform can be achieved without overturning the existing system of capitalism. The Factor Four authors write:
The idea that much of the answer to unsustainable market activity is sustainable market activity may offend both those on the right who don’t see why what they’re doing is unsustainable, and those on the left who think markets and profits can’t be used for good ends. If so, that may be the price of pragmatism. For abundant experience now emerging in diverse societies suggests a bonanza of market-based institutional innovations no less important than the technological innovations just described … Perhaps the trouble with eco-capitalism is not that it has been tried and found wanting, but that it has not yet really been tried.181
Factor Four spells out a by now common chain of argument, which has four links:182
Link 1. The key to sustainability is to make the technologies that will underpin it profitable while making polluting and resource-inefficient technologies progressively less profitable.
Link 2. This is economically feasible because, to take a key sector like energy as an example:
– fuel prices correlate negatively with fuel consumption (we observe a high, if long-term, price elasticity);183
– energy prices appear to correlate positively with economic performance, not negatively as conventional wisdom from the industrial lobby suggests: that is, cheap-energy economies tend to be wasteful and uncompetitive while dear—energy economies tend to be ingenious, innovative and highly competitive;
– higher resource prices are justified as a means of internalising external costs; and, best of all,
– a fourfold increase of resource productivity is technologically available and often cost-effective, so that no loss of well being must be feared from rising resource prices.184
Link 3. On the basis of existing experience with green taxes and economic modelling:
End-user real prices for energy and primary resources should increase by around five per cent annually for a period at least of some 20 years, preferably 40 years or more … the annual signal should be so mild that no capital destruction would result and that technological progress in average resource productivity can outweigh the price increase, thus leaving constant the annual average expenditures for energy and resources … Nonetheless, the same signal would be tremendously strong for technology development. Knowing that energy and resource prices will steadily go up by five per cent per annum for a very long period of time would serve as an extremely powerful motivation for managers and engineers to work on the efficiency revolution. Suddenly you would find hundreds of businesspeople snooping around for bonanza opportunities …185
Link 4. If we inject the productivity gains accruing from the introduction of these resource-efficient technologies into a “systems dynamic” model186 of likely global developments in population growth, industrial production, raw materials usage and environmental pollution:
A moderately optimistic development is obtained for the two per cent [productivity] gains assumption, and a truly attractive scenario [of rising food and industrial production and living standards matched by a falling rate of raw material usage and pollution] emerges from the four per cent gains assumption.187
Quod Erat Demonstrandum. The intelligent and flexible application of green taxes and charges at the micro-level will bring about the macro-result of global sustainable development via the accelerated introduction of environmental technologies.
Economic modelling supports this line of argument.188 Typical was a 1994 exercise commissioned by the European Commission, which modelled three scenarios for the six largest European economies — a “reference scenario” based on environment policy already agreed , a “policy-in-the-pipeline” scenario incorporating all environment proposals that had been the subject of an EC directive, and an “integrated scenario” based on using ecotaxation and other measures to internalise environmental costs.
For 13 areas of environmental damage, the results showed that there would be an improvement between 1990 and 2010 in only three under the business-as-usual scenario, six if policy-in-the pipeline applied, but in 10 if the ecotaxation package were implemented. In this last case there would also be an increase of 2.2 million jobs if the income from the eco-taxes were fully recycled to business as a cut in their social security contributions. Nor would these gains come at the cost of lower growth. Indeed, under the integrated scenario growth by 2010 would be one per cent higher than otherwise.189
Is such a “win-win” scenario realistic? At face value two trends seem to make it feasible. Certain eco-taxes have been successful (see Box 2) and in many cases the cost for business of adapting to them has not been as great as initially feared.190
Certainly, green taxes (and, equivalently, the removal of anti-environmental subsidies, estimated at $650 billion a year at least for the world economy191) can cut back pollution and resource depletion — if five conditions can all be broadly met.
– Tax rates are high enough (or, in the case of tradeable permits, the number of permits low enough) to meet targetted cuts in resource use or pollution per unit of output.192
– The cuts achieved in resource use or pollution emission per unit of output aren’t offset by any increase in total resource use or pollution emission;
– Resource-depleting and polluting activities aren’t shifted outside the area where the tax applies;
– The funds raised are large enough, when combined with funds from other sources, to finance sufficient investment in sustainable technology across all industry, as well as funding the budget needed for cleaning up pollution and accumulated environmental degradation;
– A strong enough alliance in support of the taxes is built, as was not the case with the 1994 UK domestic fuel tax, which had to be withdrawn because of popular protests, nor Clinton’s 1993 energy tax proposal, which was torpedoed by corporate opposition, but has been possible in Denmark where social democratic governments have enjoyed the support of the left wing Enhedslisten (Red-Green Lists) for their green taxation legislation.
Can these conditions generally be met under today’s capitalism? What follows is a survey of experience to date. While the evidence is considered in the same order as the five conditions just stated, the key interconnections among the various elements are also drawn out.
What tax rate?
Every tax has to be set at a rate and given a basis (weight, value etc). This starts off as a more or less difficult technical problem — even before the potential winners and losers from the tax come into the picture. Yet working out the likely environmental impact of a given rate of green tax is no simple business. For example, a carbon tax on coal would be expected to lead to some combination of increased use of fossil fuels with a lower carbon content (oil and natural gas), a switch to non-carbon energy sources (nuclear or renewables) and increased investment in energy conservation.
Potential margins of error are huge, starting with the reaction of the taxed capitalist firm to the tax. Will it decide to pay and carry on polluting at the old rate or introduce some form of abatement (and to what degree?). The end result will depend on how the tax affects prices, and how prices affect the demand for alternative fuels and energy conservation, keeping in mind that changes in demand will in turn affect the price of all forms of energy — often in a very volatile way — and that historical evidence of these relationships doesn’t provide a sure guide to future behaviour.
A 1991 UK study found that the rate of carbon tax needed to obtain a 20 per cent reduction in emissions — only one third of that needed to stabilise atmospheric carbon dioxide levels — ranged from 171 per cent to 23 per cent for coal, 134 per cent to 18 per cent for oil and 65 per cent to 9 per cent for oil, depending on varying but realistic assumptions about the impact of price change on demand.193
Or again, UK Treasury officials who appeared before the House of Lords’ Select Committee on Sustainable Development had to concede that they “were not 100 per cent certain” about the response in car-driving behaviour that would result from increases in petrol excise tax.194
An “energy modelling forum” carried out by Stanford University in 1990 injected an $80 carbon tax into 14 different economic models, and came up with a change in carbon dioxide emissions of between _35 and +20 per cent! US economist William Nordhaus calculates that uncertainty about the degree and impact of global warming means that the “optimal” tax rate has to double.195
An apparently surer method of reaching a given reduction target is to use tradeable permits, which fix the amount of the resource that is to be used or pollution emitted and then allow permits equal to this total to be traded. But how is the market asset (the right to pollute) to be distributed at the outset? Should it be distributed equally among the “players”, auctioned off, sold at a set price or distributed according to a more or less complicated rule?
When the US began its tradeable permit program for sulphur dioxide in 1990, existing polluters were given the right to pollute at or near existing emission levels, being sheltered by a device known as “grandfathering”, by which permits are distributed in proportion to current pollution emissions and the oldest and dirtiest industries are preserved from having to pay “too much” for their right to pollute.
However, precisely because it remains hostage to the profitability of the most polluting, grandfathering can actually slow down the introduction of cleaner technologies by reducing the cost advantage for those that are thinking of building new facilities which embody the latest innovations.196 Predictability is bought at the price of a lesser impact on pollution.
What lies behind the difficulty in establishing “the” optimal level of a green tax is the thorny question of how to establish “social marginal cost”, and whether, indeed, this concept can be expressed in numbers. For while setting a rate for a particular green tax doesn’t require establishing a precise value for the “externality” that it is designed to address, and implementation of the tax can proceed by trial and error, market-based decision-making over the environment cannot take place unless some values are assigned to environmental costs and benefits. Yet the very concept of “valuing environmental services” is fraught with problems, both of principle and in practice. We look at these issues in the section "Can social marginal cost' be established?" (See page 165.)
{{Box 2}}[see below] shows the best achievements green taxation can boast to date. Recent OECD summaries of experience with environmental taxation in OECD countries197 have revealed significant environmental improvement in only a few cases, confirming the findings of a 1989 study by Robert Hahn.198 There is no mystery here; for no private firm or industry is going to take lying down a tax set to meet a target rate of reduction in resource depletion and pollution that excessively undermines profits. Tax rates simply have to be set within a band that keeps the bulk of companies in business and allows them to turn their investment towards more resource-efficient and less polluting equipment at their own pace.
The recent debate in Britain over the rate to apply for a landfill tax tells this story clearly enough. While Friends of the Earth proposed a tax of £30 ($48) a tonne of waste in order to provide a strong recycling incentive, the Advisory Committee on Business and the Environment proposed a rate beginning at £8 ($12.80) a tonne and rising to £12 ($19) a tonne after two years. Yet, according to a 1993 Coopers and Lybrand report, even a £20 ($32) a tonne tax would lead to only 12 per cent recycling, although there would be a greater shift to incineration. The tax rates finally levied were £7($11.20) a tonne for standard waste and £2 ($3.20) a tonne for "inactive" waste which would not cause pollution. According to one sober assessment, "there is some evidence to suggest that the tax will not achieve its aims, particularly in the minimisation and recycling of domestic waste".199
What success stories there are fall into two basic categories: those where polluting technology was already on the way out, like chlorofluorocarbons (CFCs) and sulphur dioxide, and those where consumers could readily change their spending behaviour. In both cases substitutes were available or coming on line. For example, when a tax differentiation between three categories of diesel fuel was introduced in Sweden in 1991, it led to "clean" diesel's share of the market rising from one to 60 per cent within two years. 200
At the other end of the scale, the fees paid under British Colombia's "sustainability fund" are capped so that total income doesn't exceed $15 million. As a result "the current fee structure has changed behaviour only on the margin" and "most permittees lowered their discharges only in response to a number of regulations introduced by government over the past five years".201
The conditions for success for a green tax simply don't apply to the world's major polluting and resource-devouring industries. Here eco-taxes that would make a difference would have to hurt. For example, an eco-tax which aimed at "internalising the externalities" of the US car industry would involve removing subsidies ranging, according to one 1993 study, between $380 billion and $660 billion a year — roughly between seven and 12 per cent of national product, or $1500 and $2700 for every man, woman and child.202
That's because, according to G. Tyler Miller:
{In the United States one of every six dollars spent and one of every six non-farm jobs are connected to the automobile or related industries such as oil, steel, rubber, plastics, automobile services and highway construction. This industrial complex accounts for 20 per cent of the annual GNP and provides about 18 per cent of all federal taxes}.203
A recent Danish study of the level of tax needed to fully "internalise the externalities" of passenger car use came up with a real cost of driving a car of 70 cents a kilometre, only seven cents of which related to owning the car and 63 cents of which related to driving it. Assuming the car was driven 200,000 kilometres over 10 years, then covering external costs would require a vehicle tax of $4000 and a fuel price of $5 a litre!204
If the US chemical industry were forced to pay the cost of destroying all the toxic chemicals it now discharges into the environment, the annual cost (in 1986 figures) would be $20 billion, 7.5 times its yearly after-tax profit of $2.6 billion.205
Clearly, designing green taxes and tradeable pollution permits is no more a technical exercise than designing any tax. How such decisions will be made will have everything to do with the relative strength of the contending parties — in the case of a carbon tax, the oil multinationals, the energy-dependent big corporations, the governments that represent them, the Organisation of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC), non-OPEC oil-exporters and the rest of the countries of the South.
Here the fight to reach agreed targets and an international permit system for tackling global warming has been instructive. The consensus of the 2500 scientists who make up the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) is that the Earth's average temperature will rise between 0.8 and 3.5ºC during the next century, causing rising sea levels, severe storms, increasing desertification and epidemics. To halt this trend greenhouse gas emissions {have to be cut rapidly by between 60 and 80 per cent and stabilised at that level}.
Yet, only by the 1995 Berlin Conference of the Parties to the Rio global warming convention (COP1) was the US government forced to accept the concept of greenhouse gas reduction targets. By 1997, at Kyoto (COP3) the US, which emits 23 per cent of all greenhouse gases, proposed a global emissions reduction target of a mere five per cent below 1990 levels by 2012. The final agreement was for an average global cut of 5.2 per cent.
Even this token target is proving very difficult to translate into reality. At the Buenos Aires Conference of the Parties (COP4) there was no agreement on why the targets for the industrialised groups of countries were so inadequate. Big greenhouse gas emitters like the US blamed non-participating countries like Russia, and newly industrialising countries blamed industrialised economies for their poor efforts to date. The "review of adequacy", aimed at establishing what long-term level of greenhouse gases was sustainable, simply didn't take place.
While the Clinton administration finally signed the Kyoto agreement at Buenos Aires it made no serious commitment on reducing greenhouse gases due to electricity generation, and none at all on those due to road transport. So while Rio's global warming convention still has a roadmap and a process, it falls further and further behind where it needs to be.
In 1991 ecotaxation expert Scott Barrett had already noted:
{While it is difficult to compare the estimates from one study with those of another, the qualitative story is pretty clear. To lower carbon dioxide emissions very substantially would require a large carbon tax — larger, certainly, than the taxes already implemented, or for which there exist firm proposals.}206
Jean-Philippe Barde, the principal administrator of the OECD's Environmental Directorate agrees:
{We are in a "grey" area where most existing environmental taxes, including carbon taxes, are still fairly small. If we want environmental taxes to be really effective and efficient, their level must increase significantly. Carbon taxes are a case in point: in OECD countries, even a moderate carbon tax of $50 per tonne of carbon would raise approximately $150 billion (based on 1990 carbon emissions) — i.e., about 2.5 per cent of the total OECD tax revenue. Stabilising carbon dioxide emissions at 1990 levels by the year 2050 would necessitate much higher taxes. Clearly, such tax levels would imply significant economic effects and restructuring, even in a revenue-neutral perspective. The prospects for significant increases in eco-taxes are far from clear for the time being.}207
Similar impossible choices would confront a government that wanted to force privatised water supply companies to cover the costs of maintaining and repairing Britain's watersheds and rivers:
{There is little prospect of any government, however committed to the long-term sustainability of the water environment, agreeing to implement an abstraction-charging [payment for water removal] scheme which even approximates to the prescriptions for efficiency. If long-run river-flow enhancement costs were employed as the charging base, abstractors in the southern and eastern parts of England would face charges at least 10-20 times higher than the present, and in some areas an increase approaching 100-fold would be likely.}208
As the {New York Times} reported before Kyoto:
{Many experts believe that it is already too late to avoid serious climactic disruption, that the task ahead is one of keeping it from becoming truly catastrophic. The reason, [they] say, is that the world's economic and political systems cannot depart from business as usual rapidly enough.}209
These facts of life cannot be conjured away with the Factor Four argument that national capitalist economies with higher energy prices tend to be more efficient or that their proposed green tax rate increase would be "imperceptible". First, the role of high energy prices in making Japan and Switzerland more efficient economies than the US (if this is still true) begs the question as to how much, if at all, this is due to higher energy prices and whether every economy would benefit from having higher energy prices foisted upon them.
Second, even if it could be proved that "the economy" stood to gain from higher energy prices, this would not hold for many of the economy's most important individual capitalists. In an economic universe of excess capacity and massive downward pressure on costs, energy-dependent big corporations will move heaven and earth to ensure no green tax undermines their global competitive position. As McKinsey consultants Noah Walley and Bradley Whitehead wrote in the {Harvard Business Review}:
{While tough environmental standards may yield significant positive results for the economy as a whole, individual companies will actually be battling increasingly complex environmental problems at a much higher cost than before … Companies are already beginning to question their public commitment to the environment, especially since such costly obligations often come at a time when many companies are undergoing dramatic expense restructurings and layoffs.}210
The green tax utopians, like the Factor Four authors, bedazzled by the long-run benefits to the economy that their models often show, forget that competing capitalists operate, and mostly have to operate, in the short run: they cannot sacrifice their concrete immediate interest to the imaginary general good of "the economy".
Thus, it was the Ford Motor Company which in 1990 induced the governor of California to veto a fuel economy incentive system that had already been passed by the state legislature and it was a cabal of the major US manufacturers and energy producers which, in the most expensive lobbying effort ever, successfully squelched Clinton's 1993 proposal for a very mild energy tax. Similarly:
{Within the European Union, the proposal for a community-wide carbon-energy tax, designed to be the centre-piece of EU climate policy, was also weakened by excluding energy-intensive industries and making the tax conditional upon the adoption of similar measures by industrial competitors such as Japan and the US. The weakening of the tax is explained by a potent combination of concerns over competitiveness, heightened amid global recession, and some of the fiercest lobbying ever seen against an EU proposal by the fossil fuel industries.}211
Sometimes targets for green taxes do get determined a bit realistically and the consequences, in the real world of profit-making, speak volumes. For instance:
One of the most innovative tax initiatives to date appeared in the heavily polluted state of Louisiana in 1991. The state government began grading petrochemical and other companies on a scale of 50 to 100, based on their history of compliance with environmental laws, the number of people they employed for the amount of pollution they generated, and related factors. Companies with low scores lost up to half the standard tax deduction for new investment. In the first year, 12 firms agreed to cut toxic emissions enough to lower the state's total by 8.2 per cent. Many of the pollution reduction plans cost the companies more than they earned in tax credits, showing that the fear of a tarnished public image was giving the tax system added kick.212
Despite the modest reduction in total emissions achieved, this tax was so irritating to big business in Louisiana that it campaigned to have it repealed. The tax was removed from the statute book in 1992.
{{{What impact have resource efficiency gains had on total resource depletion and pollution?}}}
The next issue to assess is whether gains in resource efficiency (whether due to green taxes or not) have been offset by an increase in total resource usage or pollution emission.
Telling here is the consistent failure of the advanced industrial countries to meet targets for reducing smog-causing nitrogen oxide emissions. Because nitrogen oxides largely come from cars, rising fuel taxes and increased fuel efficiency have failed to offset the increase in total emissions, which continued to rise from 1988 to 1994, even as sulphur dioxide emissions declined slightly.213 Increased fuel efficiency went into increased overall consumption — in cars constructed (two for every new-born child!) and kilometres driven.
Despite energy efficiency in the advanced industrial world roughly doubling since 1970 world energy production continues to rise inexorably. The World Energy Council (WEC) projects increases in energy demand between 1990 and 2020 of between 30 and 98 per cent, with the 30 per cent figure derived from what it calls its "ecologically driven" scenario.
{[This] assumes a very high annual improvement in energy efficiency, a massive transfer of energy-efficient technology to those nations without it, and, consequently a very low increase in energy demand among developing countries over the next 30 years. In addition, this scenario presumes an accelerated switch to natural gas and renewable energy sources}.214
Clearly, the impact of a 30 per cent increase in energy generation on global warming will depend critically on the rate of uptake of non-traditional renewable energy technologies (solar heating, photovoltaic, wind, geothermal and tidal). This is increasing rapidly, but from a very low base. Less than two per cent of global energy comes from such sources and a detailed study by the WEC projects they will contribute less than four per cent by 2020 if current rates of implementation continue.215
In California, the site of many of {Factor Four}'s examples of the most imaginative uses of green taxes, energy use overall has increased since the early 1980s, even though there has been "modestly decreased electricity use per capita".216 A US study of households whose homes were insulated in 1982 found that 49 per cent of them did not use less energy as a result.217
The same trend holds for toxics. The latest US EPA report states:
{American industry continues to generate more toxic waste each year. In 1995, industrial companies covered by the report generated 35 billion pounds of toxic waste, three per cent more than the previous year and seven per cent more than in 1991. Some 2.2 billion pounds of these toxic chemicals were released into the air, land and water in 1995. Moreover, manufacturers' reliance on deep injection wells to dispose of toxic chemicals — a cheap way of dumping wastes on site which poses potential hazards to underground drinking water supplies — jumped nearly 20 per cent (an additional 24.5 million pounds). Furthermore, according to a 1991 report by the National Academy of Sciences, it is estimated that American business annually produces some 4.5 billion tonnes of hazardous waste, {{an amount equal to 48,000 pounds (or 100 pounds daily) of hazardous waste for every man, woman and child in the United States}}. (Emphasis added.)}218
Even 3M Corporation, which with its "Pollution Prevention Pays" (3P) plan is trumpetted as the US pioneer in corporate pollution prevention, while claiming a reduction in pollutants released of 33,000 tonnes a year between 1975 and 1989, actually increased its total output of pollution because of increases in overall production.219
None of this is surprising. Total growth always potentially offsets efficiency gains unless the goal of a green tax is the {definitive elimination} of the pollutant from the environment. While some level of pollution is allowed to enter the environment the intended reduction can always be negated and {the more expansionary the dynamic of the economic system, the greater the likelihood of this result}.
Capitalism is {nothing} if not expansionary. Once existing markets become saturated the rate of return on investment inevitably falls. This dictates permanent creation of new "needs", the unending stimulation of acquisitiveness and planned obsolescence — all driving ongoing expansion of the scale of production and ever-rising resource usage and pollution. Any interruption to this process can only take the form of an economic crisis. So, whatever the gains made at a local level, green taxes face a permanent uphill struggle to keep resource use efficiency growth ahead of total resource use growth.
The {Factor Fou}r authors are aware of this reality, conceding that "shrinking turnover may repel rather than attract capital that is seeking profitable investment". They reply:
Some of the efficiency gains are indeed achieved by doing away with nonsensical turnover. But that would not in itself mean that capital cannot be interested. After all, it was the business world itself which moved from the old-fashioned obsession with turnover to the lean and profitable firm, recognising that what matters is not the top line (total revenue) but the bottom line (net profit). More important, the better part of the examples [given in the opening chapters of Factor Four] are fully compatible with market expansion — to meet the needs of thousands of millions of people under conditions of limited resources.220
Why?
If global economic growth averages three per cent annually, resource productivity would have to increase at an annual rate above three per cent if we were to win the race. Given the proven potential in many sectors for productivity gains above 300 per cent (which is the percentage meaning of a factor of four), annual increases of 4-5 per cent would not seem an unrealistic hope, and in various times and places have already been achieved …221
Yet concede, for argument's sake, the {Factor Four} case that there is some nice profit to be made in meeting demand for a new generation of refrigerators embodying energy efficiency gains of at least 300 per cent. But operations for private profit can't stop there. To keep profits flowing, consumers have to be convinced to buy the following generation of energy-efficient refrigerators and for this whole process — involving recycling and scrapping the first generation and installing the next generation — to remain ecologically sustainable the resource efficiency gain has to be large enough to produce declining resource usage and pollution at each round.
At the same time, the more energy-efficient technology becomes, the smaller will be the proportion of energy cost in the total cost, and the less important such cost will be in the consumer
s decision to buy.
Moreover, if succeeding generations of refrigerators don’t achieve the energy gains necessary to continue reducing their overall impact on energy usage, they will still have to be sold. The manufacturers can’t abstain from profit-making simply because their rate of resource productivity gain is falling after its initial leap forward. And if the rate of return in refrigerators isn’t high enough capital will turn to other product lines, polluting or not and the organised and relentless pressure of the “sales effort” will fight any slackening of consumption.
There is, at the very least, no prima facie reason to agree that “progress in efficiency is likely to speed up and ultimately to exceed all potential market expansion for commodities”222 and to continue to do so, as it must if the “win-win result” of stable profit rates and declining resource use are to go together. This is true even if we concede that there is a logjam of energy and resource efficient prototype products and processes presently awaiting a green tax regime to attract trillions of dollars of investment.
There’s certainly no evidence for it in trends to date. While we should certainly always be wary of the vice of extrapolation, it’s surely significant that since the 1980s oil crisis no gain in energy efficiency has gone into reduced total energy usage. For example, between 1980 and 1994 energy efficiency for the OECD countries, as measured by GDP output per kilogram of oil equivalent, more than doubled — from $2.4 to $5.5 — while per capita energy use rose from 4339 to 4503 kilograms over the same period.223
In fact, the increase in Japanese energy efficiency between 1980 and 1994 facilitated an increase in energy use. Businesses as a whole reacted to increases in oil prices by more than tripling energy efficiency between 1980 and 1994 at the same time as increasing commercial energy use from 2972 to 3825 kilograms per capita and with it greenhouse gas emissions. Between 1990 and 1996 these rose by 13 per cent, even as German and UK emissions stabilised. At the same time carbon emissions in developing countries were 44 per cent above 1990 levels and 71 per cent above 1986 levels.224
Similar trends have emerged in US consumption of cars, houses, plastics in cars, bottles and cans, lead batteries, car tyres and mobile phones.225 For Western Europe over the past 25 years material and energy efficiency has improved greatly.
Typically, however, these gains have been more than outstripped by absolute increases in consumption. For instance, the efficiency of building services (lighting, heating, cooling equipment) is increasing by about one per cent per year, but the quantity of energy consumed for these purposes is increasing by two per cent per year. The technical efficiency of the car improves by 1 to 1.5 per cent per year, but this is outstripped by growth in travel (2 to 2.5 per cent per year) and the upgrading of vehicle power (0.5 per cent per year). As a result of these types of trends, European energy consumption has increased by 40 per cent since 1970. The extent of built-up land has doubled, and so on.226
Indeed, taking capitalism since 1900, the only force to date that has been able to stop the exponential growth of materials use and pollution has been recession.227 For example, the catastrophic collapse of the Russian economy between 1990 and 1996 saw carbon emissions simultaneously fall by 30 per cent.
If we look at the history of the industrialisation of nations, it has certainly been true that each newly industrialising economy has been more efficient than its predecessors because of the “leap-frogging” impact of new technology. However, this heightened resource efficiency has in no case been reflected in lower rates of resource usage and pollution output for a given rate of growth. Rather the universal pattern is that the newly industrialising capitalist economy exploits the advantage of newer technology to grow more rapidly and with greater overall through-put of natural resources. Such is the experience of the “miracle” economies of South Korea and Taiwan, which made the journey to full industrialisation more quickly — and at greater cost to the environment — than all their predecessors.
Enthusiasts for the new eco-efficient technologies, like the Factor Four authors, really can’t afford to face these realities. They dream of a wholesale renewal of capital stock involving energy-efficient buildings, closed-loop industrial production and rapidly increasing application of renewable energy, but they can’t answer such simple questions as: Could capitalism really survive if it made articles that lasted for 100 years and abandoned its relentless pressure to force up consumption (and/or military spending)? If the obsession with turnover is “nonsensical” why does every capitalist firm persist with it?
The world car industry is a case in point. While at home environmental concerns have compelled the Big Three car producers (Ford, GM and Chrysler) to accept some increases in domestic fuel taxes and they boast about their Supercar project (which is aimed at reaching fuel efficiency of three litres per 100 kilometres and producing half the carbon dioxide as today’s models), in Eastern Europe they are behind the push to prune back the region’s extensive railway network and build more motorways.
Eastern Europe has become a huge market for second-hand cars from richer Western countries. The car fleet is expanding at an annual rate of 10 per cent and the largest Western investments in the east (including the World Bank’s) have gone into car production and highway infrastructure. In 1991 the Financial Times celebrated the possibility of the old “communist” world providing a “Potential Market of 420M” cars (there are presently 501 million cars worldwide).228
Hilary F. French describes the global situation for the automobile multinationals:
The major multinational automobile companies, for example, plagued by saturated markets in the industrial world, are salivating over the “emerging markets” of Asia, Eastern Europe, and Latin America. Some three quarters of the auto factories projected to be built over the next three years are expected to be in emerging markets. European, Japanese, US and South Korean companies are competing aggressively to build these plants. General Motors recently sank some $2.2 billion into a “four-plant strategy” to build nearly identical plants simultaneously in Argentina, China, Poland and Thailand. And nine of the world’s major automakers — including Ford, General Motors and Mercedes-Benz — have set up shop in India in just the last few years. If these countries develop auto-centric transportation systems along the lines of the US model, the consequences for local air pollution, climate change and food security will be serious indeed. (Emphasis added.)229
What green tax regime could conceivably arrest the spread of the ongoing ecological catastrophe that is the motor car, the “commodity that is eating the world”, which as a provider of mobility has been compared to “using a chainsaw to cut butter”? 230 Does anyone seriously suggest that the multinational car corporations — overwhelmed with excess capacity and in many cases operating on paper-thin margins — can suspend their century-long push to convert everyone into a car-owner, or their entrenched hostility to public transport, just because our planet is choking to death? At the same time as General Motors talks greenwash at home its cars for the Chinese market will not even have catalytic converters.231
If we take global warming, it’s not surprising that eco-tax enthusiasts like the Worldwatch Institute’s Christopher Slavin and Seth Dunn can point to only one energy tax regime that has actually reduced carbon emissions. This is the Dutch carbon tax, which has the least exemptions of all existing energy taxes and in 1996 was cutting carbon emissions in that country by two per cent a year.232 However, even that tax had weaknesses that are touched on later.
Green tax evasion
Like any tax an eco-tax must be enforceable. This was an easy affair, for instance, in the US oil industry where the amount of lead in petrol could be readily monitored. It has been reasonably easy with CFCs, where production of the pollutant is restricted to a small number of companies and outlets. Yet, even while CFC production has practically been eliminated in the advanced industrial world, a thriving black market for Russian-produced CFCs still challenges the policing arrangements established under the 1987 Montreal protocol.
In the case of lead in petrol the trading permit regime that operated among US petrol refineries produced savings to refiners of about $228 million as they moved to meet Environmental Protection Agency targets for phasing lead out of petrol. However:
Given the success of this market in promoting cost savings over a period in which lead was being produced, it is important to understand why the market was successful. The lead market had two important features, which distinguish it from other markets in environmental credits. The first was that the amount of lead in gasoline could be easily monitored with the existing regulatory apparatus. The second was that the program was implemented after agreement had been reached about basic environmental goals. In particular, there was already widespread agreement that lead was to be phased out in gasoline. This suggests that the success in lead trading may not be easily transferred to other applications in which monitoring is a problem, or environmental goals are poorly defined.233
As already noted, successful environmental taxes also depend on the existence of a stable relationship between the tax base and pollution, but relationships that appear stable can become highly unstable once a tax is introduced and the targets look for ways to avoid its impact. For example, a household refuse system in Norway which required householders to get rid of their garbage in special sacks that had to be bought backfired because householders either overfilled the sacks or dumped their refuse illegally. There are also fears that the UK landfill tax will produce an epidemic of uncontrollable “fly-tipping”.
The fishing industry provides a particularly stark example of enforcement failure. In 1992 it was estimated that up to 80 per cent of fish sold in New Zealand passed through the black market, evading the permit system. According to a 1993 Greenpeace report on the world tuna industry:
Literally hundreds, if not thousands, of fishing ships operate without any monitoring or control at all. They use flags of convenience to avoid regulations, or change their names to avoid inspection … The vessels are able to move from ocean to ocean very quickly when necessary, mixing tuna caught in different regions and using different methods. For example, a boat can fill most of its hold with tuna caught in areas where there are no observers and control, and then “launder” its catch by a brief trip to the eastern Pacific, where there are inspectors and controls … Once the tuna arrives in port, it is further mixed with tuna from other ships, coming from other areas. By this point, buyers have an enormous choice of tuna, caught in different areas by different ships, and reliably identifying where and how the tuna was caught is almost impossible.234
Where environmental laws are strong on paper but unenforced (the former “communist” countries) or simply weaker (the underdeveloped world) capital will always be tempted to flow out of its existing centres of operation in search of a better rate of return, typified by the lines of maquiladora (assembly) plants on the Mexican side of the super-polluted US-Mexican border.
In the city of Mexicali, near the California border, more than a quarter of the factory operators surveyed in the late 1980s said that Mexico’s lax environmental enforcement influenced their decision to be there and a 1995 report found that roughly a quarter of maquiladora hazardous waste — some 44 tonnes daily — could not be accounted for, presumably because it is dumped in ditches.235
While some claim that there is no convincing evidence of large-scale capital flight to “pollution havens” so far,236 it’s clear that in a world economy marked by increasing capital mobility, any tax which cuts into profits past a certain point must drive investment abroad, especially where new plant is concerned.
For example, in its submission in the discussion over the UK landfill tax, the Confederation of British Industry, representing big business, laid great stress on the need to maintain international competitiveness, emphasising as well that the tax should not reduce Britain’s “natural advantage” over other European countries in still having land suitable for landfill.237
In the absence of any ability to enforce uniform green taxes internationally, the degree to which national economies can afford such taxes becomes constrained by the competition from economies with lower (or no) green tax burdens. So those economies that have gone furthest in adopting energy and other green taxes — the Scandinavian countries and the Netherlands — grant exemptions for uses that most affects the cost structures of their major industries, like electricity generation and use (Sweden and Denmark), natural gas use (Norway and Netherlands) and domestic and overseas transport fuels (Finland and Norway). The Danish government is presently demanding that Germany increase its taxes on petroleum and diesel to reduce the temptation on energy-dependent Danish companies to cross over the Danish-German border.238
Factor Four devotes half a chapter to the issue of green tax evasion, and this inevitably draws attention to the environmental havoc wreaked by unequal exchange between the imperialist centres and the underdeveloped world:
When the Ivory Coast in the two decades following independence sacrificed much of its natural treasures to the production of cash crops and other export commodities, the young nation became a hero of the international banking community. Here was a country “taking off”, enjoying a stable currency (linked to the French franc) and a “stable” political climate. Well, soon enough, the party was over. What has remained are skyscrapers, fancy hotels and an élite habituated to Western consumption styles, but otherwise widespread destitution, a devastated natural environment and political instability. Neighbouring Ghana, the current darling of the international financial institutions, is going down the same track. The Solomon Islands, much smaller than Ghana and the Ivory Coast, destroyed their forests at such a rate that even the IMF became nervous and admonished the country to adopt a more cautious pace.239
Perhaps the World Trade Organisation could calculate annual global externalities associated with each product and have these paid for by those who benefit most from the fact that they are “not reflected in social marginal cost” — the advanced industrial economies? Not if the banana trade is anything to go by. When a European network of NGOs worked with banana producers to reform the European banana-importing regime in favour of bananas produced in a “fair” and sustainable way, the proposal was blocked by the European Commission: such a reform would have been contrary to current WTO rules which forbid discrimination on the basis of the way products have been produced.240 In 1998 the WTO itself ruled against a US law forbidding the importation of shrimp caught without a device protecting endangered sea turtles.241
And what about the position of economies that have imposed energy taxes unilaterally? Are they able to impose compensating tariffs on imports produced without energy taxes (“border tax adjustments”), in order to protect themselves from competition? The WTO rules are unclear.242
None of this is surprising. The basic goal of the WTO is to deregulate international trade in the interests of multinational corporations. To accomplish that goal, all WTO agreements spell out what governments can’t do under pain of severe sanction. The only WTO agreement that doesn’t take this form is that concerning Intellectual Property Rights (IPR), which requires all signatories to pass national legislation entrenching protection of capital’s patent rights.243
Theoretically, it would be possible to create a more stringent global green tax regime if there were world institutions capable of enforcing them. Under such a “green Keynesian” set-up, economies that won “unfair advantage” through breaking agreed standards would be punished and countries with socially and environmentally benign policies rewarded.
However this global Keynesian “state”:
… is in the hands of big capital in general and finance capital in particular. Hence, with the exception of G7’s attempts to lower interest rates and stimulate demand in countries with export surpluses (especially Japan), the “global state” follows an anti-Keynesian policy, one that forces individual capitals and whole countries to cut costs, increase efficiency, and lower government spending respectively, without a second thought about the effects of this policy on capital overproduction on a global scale — of the type Karl Marx identified long ago — not to speak of the dangers of bitter trade wars, creative forms of beggar-my-neighbour policies, growing social decay, political instability, and regional trading blocs. Put another way, there is no global parliament to pass minimum wage laws and protective legislation, no World Ministries of Labour or Social Welfare, no World Ministry of Environment, no legitimate power spreading Keynesian economic literacy on an international scale … The prospects of global regulation today, organised in a truly cooperative spirit, are as poor as those of national regulation during the crisis of the 1890s, namely, zero.244
Such is capitalism today: a world system of competing national capitalist powers in which the advanced capitalist nations (the “centre”) exploit, and distort the development of, the South (the “periphery”). Within it those countries that are trying to claw their way out of underdevelopment are compelled to undercut each other for the status of preferred raw material suppliers, sub-contractors and assemblers to the big multinational corporations based in the imperialist Triad of the US, Western Europe and Japan.
The world price of a commodity like tropical timber is simply too low (90 per cent of the value of tropical timber accrues to consumer countries) for the burden of even minimal environmental taxes to be endured for very long. In this connection decisions like the 1998 Indonesian government move to cut its export tax on timber from 200 to 30 per cent in the wake of the 1997 Asian economic crisis says more than a dozen essays on ecotaxation.
Who pays?
This issue is directly linked to that of green tax evasion, for if the polluter doesn’t pay through evading a green tax, someone else will. The “polluter pays” principle has been on the books of bodies like the OECD and European Commission since 1972, albeit in a watered-down version that basically makes the polluter responsible for pollution produced after the date of adoption of the principle. Yet polluters can often offload some or all of the cost of a green tax onto other parties — consumers, communities or entire countries.
For instance, a $100-per-ton carbon tax in the US would use up on average 3.7 per cent of the spending budget of the poorest 10 per cent of households, but only 2.3 per cent among the richest 10 per cent.245 A 1991 British study predicted that a $10 per barrel (seven cents a litre) carbon tax would reduce overall household consumption by 6.5 per cent while cutting the consumption of the poorest 20 per cent of households by 10 per cent.246
The poor also pay environmentally:
The very first pollution trade made under the 1990 Clean Air Act allows plants belonging to the Tennessee Valley Authority (TVA) and Pittsburgh’s Duquesne Light to increase their sulphur dioxide emissions. These allowances were bought from Wisconsin Power & Light, which can afford to operate without them. Is it any surprise that in the counties surrounding the TVA plants the minority population is proportionately seven times larger than in Wisconsin? That the percentage of people living in poverty is nearly twice as high?
There are no simple ways to locate the point at which a pollution market can fairly be said to be “properly designed”.The Clean Air Act had hardly come into effect when Long Island Lighting sold pollution rights to AMAX Energy of Indianapolis. AMAX passes them along to utilities as incentives to use its high-sulphur coal. The utilities, burning that coal, will send acidic plumes that drift over the Adirondack Mountains, an area the Clean Air Act was specifically intended to protect.247
The 1990 California “feebate” scheme to rebate cars with higher than normal fuel efficiency and impose a fee on less-than-efficient models wouldn’t have just caught the Ferraris and Lamborghinis. The biggest impact would have been on working families with no choice but to drive their old Fords to and from work and the supermarket. The same objection holds for the vehicle-miles-of-travel (VMT) fee of three cents a kilometre proposed for Southern California and for road pricing systems that squeeze poorer drivers off the tollways.
The most dramatic recent illustration has been the ability of Britain’s private water companies to increase water and sewerage provision costs under the guise of passing on the cost of maintaining and improving watersheds and equipment. Between 1989 and 1995 real price rises averaged 39 per cent for water and 37 per cent for sewerage, with the result that in some areas pensioners and single parents living on social welfare were paying as much as nine per cent of their income for these services.248
Champions of such taxes are always quick to point out that some of the revenue gained can always be devoted to compensating those upon whom the cost most falls, but it’s difficult to find any examples in the real world. This is not only because it’s hard to draw dividing lines between those who are “worse off” and everyone else, it’s also because compensation will tend to undermine the environmental purpose of the tax (for instance, to force people to consume less energy).
Clearly, green taxes, like their traditional cousins, inevitably reflect or intensify the inequalities of the economies within which they are applied. If the 1994 UK proposal of an eight per cent hike in value-added tax on domestic fuel had not been defeated by the political outcry, some seven million households — Britain has the worst-insulated housing stock in Europe — wouldn’t have been able to afford to keep warm in winter.
In Alaska a tradeable permits system that was designed to restrict the depletion of haddock soon drove the smaller fishers, including those Indians for whom haddock fishing provided subsistence, out of business and into a sub-contractor status for the large fishing companies.249
It’s also hard to avoid the conclusion that some green taxes are directly designed by central governments to undermine the ability of local (and often more radical) authorities to implement their program. As applied by the Tory government of John Major the UK landfill tax fits squarely into this category. It was estimated to have cost local councils £150 million in 1997-8, with only £30 of this being recycled as cuts to employment and social security charges.
In the South green taxes deepen class divides even more. The majority of water permits issued under a Chilean scheme ended up in the hands of the rich farmers. Little wonder that at the sixth session of the Commission on Sustainable Development in early 1998:
There was a spirited exchange of views on the desirability of full-cost pricing of water. Some participants stressed that water was primarily a social good and that full-cost pricing would be socially inequitable, particularly in developing countries. Others emphasised that movement towards full-cost pricing, with provisions for meeting basic needs, was an essential mechanism to promote the efficient use of limited water supplies and to mobilise resources to finance the extension of drinking water and sanitation infrastructure.250
Moves to remove environmentally damaging subsidies can also, if regarded as the sole or even main treatment for resource depletion or pollution, undermine the position of the poorer producers. For example, in many Third World countries irrigation is typically supplied free-of-charge or at a very low fee, a procedure that promotes water wastage on a huge scale. However, moving to full cost pricing would ruin many producers.
Already, where water markets exist, double exploitation of the resource and the poorest users can result.
In India’s southern state of Tamil Nadu, well-owners pump groundwater, sometimes with the benefit of subsidised electricity, and sell it to intermediaries who in turn sell it to poor households lacking a piped water supply. The poor thus gain access to water, but may pay as much as 10 times more for it than wealthier households connected to the public water system.251
The international trade in toxic waste provides graphic confirmation of the devastating results of green tax evasion. The advanced capitalist world produces 90 per cent of the world’s annual output of 400 million tonnes of hazardous waste. It is almost impossible to keep track of these wastes but experts reckon that at least 30 million tonnes cross national borders, with a high percentage going to poorer countries. As green taxes on these wastes have climbed in countries like the US (up to about $250 a ton), African countries have been willing to accept shipments for as low as $2.50 a ton in order to get their hands on foreign exchange.252
Just as damning is the ability of Dutch environment policy, regarded as the most advanced in Europe, to operate by exporting its burden of pollution:
The emission of various polluting substances has decreased during the past few years although economic growth has continuously increased. The most important exceptions, however, are carbon dioxide emissions, mainly from growing transport intensity, and waste. These failures of policy are obvious.
What is hidden and therefore not discussed within Dutch society is that during the ten years between 1985 and 1995, the use of primary (newly produced) metals increased very substantially with a range of environmental impacts in the Netherlands and abroad, particularly in developing countries … So within the Netherlands the environment may be cleaner, with some important exceptions, but the total Dutch environmental burden on the planet is increasing. Gains in pollution control are being overtaken by volume growth, mainly associated with resource and land consumption.253
What happens to a global eco-tax proposal that would be fair? Consider the eminently just scheme of Indian environmentalists Anil Agarwal and Sunita Narain made at Rio — to base the initial allocation of tradeable permits in greenhouse gases on the basis of population.254 India and China would then get the lion’s share and the advanced industrial economies, responsible for 75 per cent of emissions, would have to purchase a lot of permits from the South, settling some of the ecological debt accrued through a century of carbon dioxide generation. The wealth transfer to the South could be anywhere between $480 billion and $1 trillion, depending on the tax model adopted — equitable but an idle fantasy in today’s world.
Would green taxes raise sufficient income to fund needed environment budgets?
Green tax economists engage in permanent debate about the “power” of a tax needed to achieve a given cut in resource use or pollution. Yet there is general agreement on one issue — these taxes should be made “revenue-neutral” by introducing offsetting cuts in taxes on wages, profits and employers’ social security contributions.
However, if the overall tax take remains unaltered then the introduction of green taxes leaves unaddressed a central reason for the ongoing environmental crisis — the totally inadequate level of government expenditure on environmental clean-up and protection. Moreover, inasmuch as the taxes are successful in reducing pollution and resource depletion they will supply less and less funds to the treasury (and, potentially, to the environment budget). Everything will then depend on whether green taxes have pushed private industry toward non-polluting and resource-efficient technologies on a sufficiently large scale.
The heart of the problem is that there is no unambiguous “double dividend” of sufficient size to be had from the imposition of a green tax. A tax that works effectively against pollution will put less revenue in the coffers (as with the Swedish sulphur tax255) and a green tax that can be a stable source of income (and hence potentially replace other, less “efficient”, taxes) won’t be effective enough against pollution. Such is the case with a carbon tax, which, according to some models, could in theory collect up to 10 per cent of world product256 before cutting back carbon dioxide emissions fast enough to forestall global warming.
Thus, one edge of the “double-edged sword” of ecotaxation is always blunter than the other. Paul Ekins summarises the experience of the Nordic countries with carbon taxes:
Tax rates have tended to be increased and some new taxes have been introduced, especially by Denmark. It is hard to know how environmentally effective the taxes have been. Where the tax rates have been increased, but the revenues have not by the same amount, it is possible that the taxes’ incentive effects are working — for instance, lubrication oil in Norway. Similarly, where revenues have increased more than taxes, then the incentive effect would appear to be weak — for instance, air pollution in France. (Emphasis added.)257
The OECD itself has admitted that the shift to ecotaxation may be useful cover for pursuing other taxation objectives. It says of Swedish environmental taxes:
It seems fair to say that, without the opportunity offered by the need felt to reduce income taxes, while keeping the total volume intact, environmental taxes would not have been introduced to the extent that is now the case.258
According to David Malin Roodman “more fully taxing pollution could raise more than $1 trillion worldwide, which could be used to cut taxes on wages and profits by up to 15 per cent”.259 Yet this $1 trillion income, even if politically achievable, would not necessarily be accompanied by a sufficiently rapid reduction in pollution nor lead to any increase in public expenditure on environmental conversion and clean-up.
The Factor Four authors don’t address these issues. In their book, “government” is synonymous with bureaucracy, inertia and high-cost solutions. The unaddressed assumption is that once correctly designed green taxes have been set in place those “hundreds of businesspeople snooping around for bonanza opportunities” will be sufficient to reverse the spiral of environmental degradation and introduce a virtuous circle of competition in green products and production methods.
Even on the extremely hopeful assumption that the present lobby of polluters wouldn’t have the political clout to stop the introduction of a revenue-neutral green tax of the scope required, the adequacy of the total tax take for the job of, say, helping fund renewable energy conversion is never seriously addressed.
However, it’s been clear, at least since Rio, that seriously getting to grips with environmental degradation demands massive expenditure on clean-up, technology conversion and improving resource efficiency well beyond the scope of any green tax system.
Whenever environmentalists, economists and the odd concerned politician seriously address the issue the analogies are always of World War II efforts, the Marshall Plan, the Manhattan Project and the Apollo space programs — massive emergency mobilisations of government funds to beat a powerful and menacing enemy.260
Not surprisingly, one of the loudest laments of Earth Summit +5 was that the funds that Agenda 21 outlined as necessary to fund its (inadequate) program — $561.1 billion a year including 0.7 per cent of GDP from the advanced industrial countries — are nowhere to be found: indeed since Rio official aid from the advanced industrial countries to the South has fallen, from 0.32 to 0.27 per cent of GDP ($59 billion in 1995).261
Even if this 0.7 per cent were forthcoming, it would return to the South only a fraction of what it loses each year to the North in repayments on its accumulated debt burden and the expatriation of the assets of its ruling elites. Between 1982 and 1990, in debt service alone, the advanced capitalist economies received $418 billion more from the Third World than the Third World received in aid.
Again, the clean-up cost of a regional environmental disaster like the US-Mexican border is reckoned at $8 billion, but the North American Development Bank, set up under the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) to fund such projects, started with a total capital of $112 million.262
On a national scale the Dutch National Environmental Policy Plan is along with Denmark’s and Switzerland’s Energy 2000 plans the most advanced in the world, but still aims to cut greenhouse gas emissions by only five per cent by 2000. To achieve this goal annual subsidies to public transportation were recently raised to $5.7 billion (1.6 per cent of GDP) and fully ten per cent of the surface transportation budget goes to bicycle facilities. Natural gas and renewable energy use are to be increased and the energy efficiency of buildings and appliances improved. (Petrol and cars are already heavily taxed.)263 To implement the still inadequate Dutch plan would require total government spending on the environment to rise to three or four per cent of GDP. (For the OECD countries spending on environmental protection typically runs at between 1.5 and 2 per cent of GDP, with Australia at a shameful 0.8 per cent.)264
In 1971 Barry Commoner estimated that the cost of converting ecologically faulty technology along ecologically sound lines would require that “most of the nation’s resources for investment would need to be engaged in the task of ecological reconstruction for at least a generation”.265 Spanish environmentalist Joaquín Araujo more recently confirmed the order of magnitude of Commoner’s estimate. Spending needed to make serious and rapid inroads into agricultural and industrial recycling, conversion to solar and other renewables, water conservation, reforestation, shifting to ecologically sound agriculture and expanding public transport would have to run at 15 per cent of GDP a year, between 75 and 100 per cent of total investment spending for an average OECD country.266 In terms of global production we are talking of sums in the order of $4-5 trillion — four to five times Roodman’s figure of potential global green tax revenue.
How are green taxes that are acceptable to business even remotely likely to bring such sums into being, especially when national economies are engaged in a “race to the bottom” in company tax rates? The tax rates needed would be so steep as to reproduce on a global scale the quandary of the US petroleum industry for which full compliance with the Clean Air Act would have cost refineries $37 billion, $6 billion more than the book value of the entire industry.267
Those who have approached such issues as global warming in precisely the opposite direction as the Factor Four authors — first calculating the cost of reversing trends and then the tax rate implied — reach the same sort of conclusion. For instance, Thomas Schelling writes of the economics of global warming:
A carbon tax sufficient to make a big dent in the greenhouse problem would have to be roughly equivalent at least to a dollar per gallon motor fuel, and for the United States alone such a tax on coal, petroleum and natural gas would currently yield close to half a trillion dollars per year in revenue. No greenhouse taxing agency is going to collect a trillion dollars per year in revenue; and no treaty requiring the United States to levy internal carbon taxation, keeping the proceeds, would be ratified by the Senate. Reduce the tax by an order of magnitude and it becomes imaginable, but then it becomes trivial as greenhouse policy.
Schelling who, as far as one can judge, is no friend of “big government”, concludes that the only feasible plan of attack on greenhouse is a repeat of the Marshall Plan for European reconstruction after the Second World War. This involved expenditure of around 1.5 per cent of US GDP and five per cent of European GDP in its first year alone.268
Competition and discount rates
It’s obvious that capitalism is an economy made up of competing capitalists, for whom green taxes will, depending on their cost structure, be more or less tolerable. Any specific green tax proposal will always tend to create winners and losers among them. Is it possible, through some carefully designed green tax regime, to harmonise competing and conflicting interests? The Factor Four authors look at office building stock, “a system of incentives and institutional structures to make buildings use about ten times as much energy as they should do, be less healthful and comfortable than they should be, and cost more to build than they should do”.269
Yet they claim that it is possible, by paying designers and architects on the basis of energy saved rather than a percentage of total building cost, to produce integrated resource-efficient design. However:
Even if we solve all those problems, we’ll still have more than 20 other parties to the building process who still have their own perverse incentives. Any of these parties can be a show-stopper. Thus, making markets work properly to produce cost-effective buildings is an unusually complex institutional problem requiring sustained and concentrated attention by practitioners, their professional societies, their regulators, other public-policy bodies and other market actors.270
Thus regulators testing whether buildings are actually meeting designed energy-efficiency projections will clash with builders under pressures to cut corners (and who may have “gone out of business” by the time any failure to meet standards is established). Financiers whose need for a quick return on investment predisposes them to install lower-cost, less energy efficient equipment will conflict with future lessees who demand an environment in which “their” workers can work more efficiently.
The reality the Factor Four authors never quite address is that to get capitalists to invest in a particular project the rate of return can’t deviate too much from some industry standard “hurdle rate” (say 15 per cent) without the shareholders getting restless. Yet to operate different industrial activities in an environmentally benign way, that is, one that takes account of the differing rhythms of various ecological cycles, requires that the rate of return be able to vary. (Of course, a planned economy pursuing environmental objectives can allow for this, even to the point of fully subsidising some activities, like public transport.)
Trying to strongarm the “market” into operating in the interest of the environment also presents particular difficulty when assessing which discount rate to use in evaluating competing investment projects.271 The way discount rates are typically set disadvantages renewable technologies because these more often than not have a high initial capital cost and low running costs whereas fossil fuel based systems have a lower initial capital cost and high running costs. One study made for Western Australia’s Renewable Energy Advisory Council showed how sensitive the cost of power generated by a solar electric power station was to the discount rate adopted. A 4 per cent discount rate yielded a power cost of 12.3 cents a kilowatt-hour; 8 per cent gave 17.1 cents a kilowatt-hour; 15 per cent gave 26.8 cents; and at 30 per cent it reached 49.7 cents.272
The pressure for an acceptable rate of return on capital invested, internalised in the discount rates most typically used — by capitalist governments as well as private firms — thus tips the “playing field” against environmentally sustainable investments that will benefit future generations. In the words of US economist Shimon Awerbuch:
For such long-lived benefit streams, the application of the private discount rate may incorrectly allocate resources since this rate is based on the time preferences of individual, finite-lived, investors. But society … continues in perpetuity. This suggests the need to derive a discount rate for projects with long-lived benefit streams, which reflect society’s time preferences.273
It follows that for a company which has sunk billions of dollars in a polluting technology and may even have covered the costs of the investment, it will be “rational” to continue using this capital stock and to suppress, if possible, new technology altogether and to lobby governments not to favour its development. This, in a nutshell, is the story of the very slow uptake of solar thermal and photovoltaic energy, which still receives far less in US federal subsidies than nuclear fusion.274 It is also why it was “rational” — it maximised “net present value” — for whaling companies to hunt the species to near extinction.
For the economy as a whole, it is simply not possible under generalised market production to derive a “social” discount rate that would guide the rate of resource depletion towards some presumed “optimum”. The very concept of “society’s time preferences” implies some social decision that reflects the best possible compromise between the competing demands of environmental health and development. Such a decision can only be reached in a social context where all the most important economic decisions are made socially — rather than via the monetary policies imposed by the central banks of competing capitalist economies.